Capitalisn't

Poverty in America: Terrible Scourge or a Measurement Error?

Episode Summary

Perhaps the biggest evidence that capitalism in America doesn’t work, at least not for everyone, is growing income inequality and the persistence of poverty. But what is the current state of poverty and inequality in the United States? Why do debates still persist about whether poverty has been eradicated? What do the numbers and official statistics tell us, and should we believe them? What do personal stories and experiences with poverty tell us that data cannot? If poverty has indeed been eradicated, what led to that achievement – and if it still persists, what more can be done to abolish it? Last year on this podcast, we did a series about this topic, and we found these episodes to be surprising and more informative than most of the debates about poverty you’ll hear on the news. So, we wanted to condense that series down into a single episode that captures all of the highlights. The first speaker is former U.S. Senator Phil Gramm (R-TX), who argues in his recent book, "The Myth of American Inequality," that poverty is vastly overstated because official government data does not include transfer payments. The second is Princeton sociologist and Pulitzer Prize-winning author Matthew Desmond, who argues in his recent book, "Poverty, by America," that poverty is a terrible scourge, that we have made no progress, and that it is a moral outrage. The result is a nuanced, surprising, and informative debate on a multifaceted but important issue – leaving our hosts, as well as, by extension, our listeners – to formulate their own takeaways on what we can all do about them.

Episode Notes

Perhaps the biggest evidence that capitalism in America doesn’t work, at least not for everyone, is growing income inequality and the persistence of poverty. But what is the current state of poverty and inequality in the United States? Why do debates still persist about whether poverty has been eradicated? What do the numbers and official statistics tell us, and should we believe them? What do personal stories and experiences with poverty tell us that data cannot? If poverty has indeed been eradicated, what led to that achievement – and if it still persists, what more can be done to abolish it?

Last year on this podcast, we did a series about this topic, and we found these episodes to be surprising and more informative than most of the debates about poverty you’ll hear on the news. So, we wanted to condense that series down into a single episode that captures all of the highlights. The first speaker is former U.S. Senator Phil Gramm (R-TX), who argues in his recent book, "The Myth of American Inequality," that poverty is vastly overstated because official government data does not include transfer payments. The second is Princeton sociologist and Pulitzer Prize-winning author Matthew Desmond, who argues in his recent book, "Poverty, by America," that poverty is a terrible scourge, that we have made no progress, and that it is a moral outrage.

The result is a nuanced, surprising, and informative debate on a multifaceted but important issue – leaving our hosts, as well as, by extension, our listeners – to formulate their own takeaways on what we can all do about them.

Episode notes:

Episode Transcription

 You  know,  the  fundamentals  of  American  society  are  breaking  down,  especially  in  the  labor  market  and  the  housing  market  for  the  American  poor,  and  it  kind  of  is  a  recipe  for  spinning  more  to  stay  in  the  same  place.

The  thing  I  want  you  to  understand  is,  I  want  to  reform  this  system  not  because  I'm  trying  to  be  mean  to  people,  but  because  I  love  people.  Because  I  think  the  current  system  is  keeping  people  down.

I'm  Bethany  McLean.  Did  you  ever  have  a  moment  of  doubt  about  capitalism  and  whether  greed's  a  good  idea?  And  I'm  Luigi  Zingales.  We  have  socialism  for  the  very  rich  rugged  individualism  for  the  poor.

And  Mrs.  Capital  isn't  a  podcast  about  what  is  working  in  capitalism.  First  of  all,  tell  me  is  there's  some  society  you  know  that  doesn't  run  on  greed?  And  most  importantly,  what  is  it?

We  ought  to  do  better  by  the  people  that  get  left  behind.  I  don't  I  don't  think  we  should  have  killed  the  capital  system  in  the  process.  - So,  Luigi,  here's  a  simple  question  for  you.  What's  the  most  prominent  argument  against  capitalism?

- I  think  if  we  try  to  synthesize  all  the  arguments  we  have  heard  in  the  last  few  decades,  two  words  come  immediately  to  mind,  poverty  and  inequality.  - Everyone  has  read  Tomas  Piketty's  capital  in  the  21st  century.

Okay,  well,  many  people  at  least  have  it  on  their  bookshelf  often  pretend  to  have  read  it.  me  among  them.  The  core  of  the  argument  is  that  inequality  in  the  United  States  in  Europe  is  rising  back  toward  pre -World  War  I  levels.

The  core  idea  is  that  income  is  stagnant  for  those  in  the  bottom  50 %  while  it's  exploding  for  those  at  the  top.  But  it's  not  just  Piketty  and  Saez,  even  the  census  viewer,  report  that  the  poverty  rate  in  2021  in  the  United  States  after  you  remember  all  the  tax  trials  credit  that  we  pay  all  the  money  we  pay  with  the  stimulus  package  for  COVID,

etc.  After  all  of  that  was  still  11 .6%,  meaning  that  37 .9  million  people  in  the  United  States  were  living  in  poverty.  That's  almost  like  four  New  York  cities  of  people  living  in  poverty.

At  the  same  time,  according  to  the  Congressional  Budget  Office,  the  richest  1 %  make  84  times  in  the  United  States.  much  as  the  bottom  20 %  in  2019.  But  what  if  that's  all  completely  wrong?

So  argue  former  U .S.  Senator  Phil  Graham  and  economists  Robert  Eklund  and  John  Early  in  their  book,  which  is  entitled  "The  Myth  of  American  Inequality,  How  Government  Biases  Policy  Debate."  That's  a  big  title,

"The  Myth  of  Inequality,"  but  the  argument  is  actually  pretty  simple.  It  turns  out  in  the  way  the  Census  Bureau  measures  poverty  and  inequality,  it  does  count  non -cash  transfers,  such  as  Medicare  and  Medicaid,  food  stamps,

and  refundable  tax  credits  and  more.  In  2017,  the  last  year,  with  all  the  data  available,  according  to  Graham,  households  in  the  bottom  20 %  of  the  income  distribution  actually  received  a  full  $45 ,000  in  government  transfers.

More  than  a  lot  of  people  receive  as  their  annual  salary.  So  the  authors  argue  that  thanks  to  this  payment,  the  percentage  of  people  living  in  poverty.  in  the  United  States  has  plummeted  to  only  1 .1 %  in  2015.

Their  book  is  also  in  part  a  policy  prescription.  The  authors  write  this,  "The  explosion  of  transfer  payments  following  the  war  on  poverty  has  caused  a  significant  number  of  prime  orca  age  persons  to  become  detached  from  the  economy.

That  disengagement  from  the  world  of  work  has  denied  them  the  opportunity  to  benefit  from  the  extraordinary  economic  progress  that  has  occurred  in  the  Le  Pen."  50  years,  and  is  also  the  single  largest  cause  of  income  inequality  in  post -war  America.

In  other  words,  people  who  are  getting  these  transfer  payments  just  need  to  get  off  their  butts  and  work  more.  So  their  prescriptions  are  very  simple,  and  if  you  want  old -fashioned,  is  to  remove  the  government  disincentives  to  work  by,

among  other  things,  adding  states  implement  work  requirements  for  public  assistance  programs  and  to  reform  elementary  and  secondary  education  to  make  sure  that  maximizes  the  chance  of  success  of  people.

So  just  so  our  listeners  know  this  is  part  of  a  two -part  series  we're  going  to  do  on  poverty  and  inequality  and  we're  going  to  bring  in  the  sociologist  Matthew  Desmond  next  for  a  different  perspective.

It  seems  to  me  that  there  are  two  separate  arguments  in  your  work,  right?  One  is  about  inequality.  inequality,  which  is  nowhere  near  what  people  think.  And  the  other  is  about  poverty,  which  is  also  nowhere  near  what  people  think.

Let's  start  with  poverty.  Can  you  explain  that  one  to  our  listeners?  Well,  when  the  Census  Bureau  started  measuring  household  income,  which  is  the  fundamental  statistical  building  block  of  our  measure  of  poverty  and  our  measure  of  inequality,

they  didn't  have  the  statistics.  statistical  ability  to  measure  the  value  of  in -kind  payments.  For  example,  food  stamps.  Another  in -kind  contribution  would  be  where  government  pays  for  Medicaid  or  government  pays  for  rent  subsidies.

There  are  over  a  hundred  federal  programs,  but  the  Census  Bureau  does  not  count  the  value  of  those  transfers.  payments  as  income  to  people  who  receive  them.

Also,  the  Census  Bureau  does  not  take  into  account  taxes,  including  tax  credits.  So  in  total,  for  poor  people,  about  88 %  of  all  transfer  payments  from  the  government  are  not  counted  as  income  in  measuring  the  poverty  rate.

And  when  you  count  that  income  and  you  count  taxes  as  income  lost,  then  the  picture  changes  completely  in  terms  of  the  poverty  rate  and  in  terms  of  income  inequality.

So  your  argument,  in  effect,  collapses  the  difference  between  cash  and  a  transfer  payment.  But  isn't  there  a  difference  in  the  sense  that  a  person  has  a  choice,  how  to  spend  the  first  one,

and  no  choice  at  all  with  the  second  one?  I  keep  thinking.  thinking  a  little  bit  about  the  famous  Marie  Antoinette  quote  that  she  didn't  actually  say  let  them  eat  cake.  Isn't  this  a  little  tiny  bit  of  let  them  eat  Medicaid?

No,  you  can  argue  that  the  benefits  government  provides  are  not  worth  what  they  cost,  but  you  can't  argue  that  food  stamps  aren't  worth  anything,

which  is  what  the  Census  Bureau  is  in  essence  arguing.  So  let's  now  move  to  the  inequality.  inequality.  It  seems  that  you  are  suggesting  that  even  on  a  pre -tax  base,

the  income  inequality  has  not  gone  up  from  1980  to  2017.  Is  that  correct?  - No,  we  argue  that  the  pre -tax  inequality  has  risen  substantially  in  point  because  the  labor  force  participation  rate  among  the  bottom  20 %  of  income.

earners  has  declined  from  68 %  to  36%.  So  earned  income  inequality  has  grown,  but  transfer  payments  have  grown  faster  than  earned  income  inequality.

Taxes  are  more  progressive  today  than  they  were  in  1967,  so  that  the  level  of  inequality  is  actually  lower  today.  today,  very  slightly,

than  it  was  in  1967,  and  in  fact  slightly  lower  than  it  was  in  1947.  So  if  you  believe  in  the  dignity  of  work,  isn't  it  still  a  problem  that  earned  income  has  diverged  so  dramatically,

even  if  we  agree  transfer  payments  have  compensated  for  much  of  it?  Isn't  there  a  problem  with  how  our  modern  economy  is  structured?  And  I'd  point  to  a  2020  GAO  report  about  federal  social  safety.

net  programs  and  the  headline  is  that  millions  of  full -time  workers  still  rely  on  federal  health  care  and  food  assistance  programs,  most  of  them  work  for  private  sector  employees  including  some  of  America's  biggest  companies.

So  isn't  part  of  the  issue  dignity  of  work  and  the  way  in  which  the  labor  market  works  these  days  such  that  even  people  who  work  full -time  have  to  get  federal  safety  net  benefits?

Well,  the  level  of  income  of  bottom  income.  20 %  earners  who  actually  work  has  risen  pretty  dramatically  in  the  last  50  years.

The  value  of  college  education  has  risen  by  a  very  large  amount  and  the  differential  between  people  who  have  human  capital  and  people  who  don't  have  much  human  capital.

It  shows  up  in  the  marketplace,  but  the  two  two  things  that  I  believe,  and  the  book  analyzes  and  presents  statistics  on,  that  we  could  do  to  eliminate  earned  income  inequality  or  to  reduce  it  is  a  better  way  of  saying,

if  you  had  a  mandatory  work  requirement  for  welfare,  to  keep  people  in  the  labor  market  where  opportunity  is  and  where  skills  are  developed,  and  if  you  have  a  a  more  effective  education  system,

especially  in  the  inner  cities  that  made  it  possible  for  more  people  from  poor  families  to  go  to  college  and  gave  them  the  tools  when  they  got  to  college  that  allowed  them  to  major  in  the  areas  where  income  is  high  that  we  could  reduce  earned  income  inequality  and  look.

look,  I  think  we  ought  to  pursue  equality  of  opportunity  as  a  basic  right.  Obviously,  there  are  limits  to  what  government  can  do.

If  my  mother  loved  me  and  your  mother  didn't  love  you,  there's  no  government  program  that's  going  to  be  able  to  eliminate  that,  but  providing  quality  education,  and  we  present  the  hard  data  about  school  choice.

I'm  not  not  sure  that  school  choice  in  competition  is  the  best  way  to  deal  with  failing  schools,  especially  in  the  inner  cities,

but  it  performs  better  than  the  public  education  system  that  we  have  now.  The  statistics  are  overwhelming  and  irrefutable,  if  that's  the  case.  - So  Charles  Calamirus  wrote  this  in  a  very  favorable  review  of  your  book.

He  wrote,  wrote,  "Increased  earned  income  inequality  is  the  natural  consequence  of  redistributive  policies.  If  one  can  enjoy  median  household  consumption  without  earning  any  income,

the  incentive  to  work  is  substantially  diminished."  This  largely  explains  the  growing  distance  between  earned  and  total  income  for  poor  households.  Do  you  agree  with  that  interpretation  or  would  you  argue  there's  a  little  more  to  it?

Well,  I  think  the  correlation  is  very  high.  When  we  had  the  explosion  of  transfer  payments,  the  labor  force  participation  rate  fell  from  68 %  to  36%.

There's  no  debate  about  that.  The  bottom  60 %  of  earners  in  America,  when  you  count  all  transfer  payments  and  you  take  away  all  income  paid  out  in  taxes,

the  bottom  60 %  of  a...  have  similar  incomes  and  so  the  reward  for  working  if  you  have  a  low  skill  levels  very  low.

The  problem  is  of  course  if  you  don't  work,  you  don't  get  on  the  job  training,  you  don't  accumulate  skills  and  you  don't  move  up  as  the  economy  moves  up.

You  can  think  of  the  economy  as  an  escalator  escalator.  If  you  get  on  it,  the  escalator  is  moving  up  because  of  a  growth  in  the  economy  and  productivity.  But  if  you  don't  get  on  the  escalator,

you're  just  simply  dependent  on  government  transfer  payments  for  income.  And  unfortunately,  many  poor  people  in  America  today  have  fallen  into  that  trap.

trap.  And  let  me  just  say,  I  failed  third,  seventh  and  ninth  grades.  Neither  of  my  parents  graduated  from  high  school.  I  have  often  said  to  my  mother  who's  now  passed  away  that  we  were  lucky  that  the  welfare  program  didn't  exist  when  I  was  growing  up,

because  if  it  existed,  she  might  have  taken  it  and  our  lives  might  have  been  different.  Now  she  argued  she  would  never  take  it.  it,  but  the  truth  is  everyone  she  would  know  would  be  taking  it.

People  would  look  down  on  her  for  not  taking  it.  So  I  want  people,  I  believe  there's  extraordinary  ability  and  ordinary  people,  I  think  in  the  worst  school  system  in  this  country,

that  there  are  talented  people  that  are  never  discovered.  I  didn't  learn  to  read  until  I  was  in  the  10th  grade.  And  my  guess  is  a  lot  a  lot  of  people  out  there  that  are  like  me.

So  the  thing  I  want  you  to  understand  is  I  want  to  reform  this  system  not  because  I'm  trying  to  be  mean  to  people,  but  because  I  love  people.  Because  I  think  the  current  system  is  keeping  people  down.

Have  you  heard  anything  in  the  various  critiques  of  your  book  or  in  discussions  with  people?  Have  you  heard  anything  that  resonated  with  you?  that  changed  your  mind  that  made  you  say,  I  wish  we  had  taken  this  into  account.

We  missed  this.  - I  would  say  this,  Bethany,  I've  been  surprised  that  there  haven't  been  more  effective  attacks  on  the  book.  If  I  were  attacking  the  book,

I  would  say,  okay,  the  numbers  are  right,  but  those  numbers  are  misleading  and  that  food  stamps  aren't  really  worth  what  they  call  it.  If  you  went  out  and  said  to  people,

you're  getting  $90  worth  of  food  stamps  this  week,  I'll  give  you  $85  for  the  food  stamps,  would  they  take  it?  Some  of  them  would.  Yeah.  Now,  I  don't  know  why  people  have  not  made  the  argument.

Maybe  if  you  accept  that  argument,  then  you  get  into  a  debate  that  I've  had  at  Chicago  and  Harvard,  and  that  is...  Should  we  be  doing  all  of  this  differently?

Given  that  we're  providing  now  almost  $50 ,000  for  the  average  household  in  the  bottom  20 %  of  income  recipients  Should  we  look  at  whether  we  need  over  a  hundred  federal  welfare  programs?

Should  we  look  at  whether  providing  all  these  things  is  as  valuable  as  is  simply  finding  a  way  of  giving  people  the  money.  Now  I  haven't  made  a  decision  about  that  as  to  where  I  stand  on  it,

but  I  think  it  is  certainly  a  subject  worthy  of  debate.  Milton  Friedman  argued  for  guaranteed  annual  income.  Now  I  can  see  problems  with  it,

but  what  do  I  see  problems  with  what  we're  doing?  So  that's  an  area  that  should  be  explored.  All  I'm  trying  to  do,  I'm  not  trying  to  end  the  debate.

I'm  trying  to  start  a  debate.  We're  spending  a  lot  of  money.  We  need  to  admit  it.  We  need  to  show  the  figures.  And  then  we  need  to  debate.  Could  we  do  this  better?  So  Luigi,

what  did  you  think  was  the  most  interesting  part  of  our  interview?  I  was  pretty  surprised  by  how  much  money  we  actually  transfer  to  the  bottom  20  percent  of  the  in -constribution.

But  in  a  positive  way,  not  in  a  negative  way,  I  don't  want  to,  in  any  way,  sounds  like  I  want  to  reduce.  But  the  point  that  we  don't  factor  in  in -kind  payment  is  pretty  remarkable.

I  know  that  you  are  less  excited  about  adding  Medicare,  but  I  think  that  Medicare  and  Medicaid  paid.  are  real  value  to  transfer  to  poor  people.  Oh,  I  agree  with  you.  I  think  they're  real  value,

too.  And  I  agree.  Transfers  in  the  form  of  Medicaid  are  real  money.  I  guess  I  just  questioned  whether  they're  dollar -for -dollar  real  money.  And  I  think  Graham  would  admit  that  that's  a,  or  agree  that  that's  a  question  you  can  ask.

I  mean,  if  I  get  a  dollar  of  income  and  I  get  to  spend  that  however  I  choose  and  you  get  a  dollar.  dollar  of  Medicaid  and  you  only  get  to  spend  it  if  you're  sick  in  a  very  specific  place,

I  don't  think  that  the  two  dollars  are  equivalent.  The  sicker  you  get,  the  richer  you  are  because  the  sicker  you  get,  the  more  Medicaid  you  use,  therefore,  the  richer  you  are.  There's  something  a  little  bit  screwed  up  about  that.

I  can't  help  thinking  it's,  you  know,  Rhianne  Twinette  did  not  say  let  them  eat  cake,  but  this  is  a  little  bit  of  let  them  eat  Medicaid.  I  disagree  because  honestly,  we  are  actually  trying  to  force  people  to  get...  health  insurance,

right?  Part  of  what  Obamacare  was  about  is  to  force  everybody  into  enrolling  in  health  insurance.  Medicare  and  Medicaid  are  the  most  generous  health  insurance  that  you  can  get  in  the  United  States.

In  the  private  market,  you  cannot  get  an  insurance  with  zero  deductible  and  zero  payment.  It's  like  impossible.  So  I  think  that  we  are  actually  more  than  dollar  for  dollar.

I  agree  with  you  that  they  don't  feel  the  same,  but  again  the  question  is  what  are  we  measuring  for  what  purpose?  If  we  are  measuring  is  the  person  who  is  richer,  how  many  times  richer  he  feels  or  how  big  the  difference  in  that  situation  because  we  are  forcing  the  rich  person  to  have  health  insurance  anyway,

he's  not  free  to  choose.  He  has  to  get  health  insurance.  So  for  that  comparison  purpose,  I  think  it's  fine  to  treat  it  dollar  for  dollar.  If  you  are  saying  in  an  abstract  sense,

if  people  were  given  the  choice,  would  prefer  do  something  else?  Absolutely.  Yeah.  You  know,  that  actually  is  a  fair  point  that  if  you're  very  well  off,  you  still  have  to  spend  the  dollars  getting  health  insurance.

At  least  it's  a  really  bad  idea  not  to  do  that.  So,  I  think  you  have  more...  convinced  me  with  the  side  point  Medicaid  dollars  aren't  as  easy  to  spend  as  you  would  think  given  the  difficulty  in  finding  doctors  who  will  take  that  insurance.

Okay.  So  another  aspect  of  fun  and  games  with  numbers  is  the  numbers  look  really  different  if  you're  talking  the  top  20%,  the  top  quintile  versus  the  bottom  quintile  versus  the  top  1 %  versus  the  top  0 .1%.

And  I  was  thinking  and  wondering  if  you'd  agree  that  that  that  might  explain  or  help  explain  why  Graham's  analysis  seems  to  fly  in  the  face  of  observed  reality,  by  which  I  mean  this  analysis  seems  to  imply  a  very  equal  America.

And  yet  we  have  all  these  stories  of  30 -year -olds  with  master's  degrees  who  can't  buy  a  home  and  a  single  mom  working  two  jobs  who  can't  afford  an  emergency  medical  payment  and  perhaps  even  more  to  the  point.

You  know,  stories  about  and  truth  about  people  being  priced  out  of...  cities,  coastal  cities,  and  even  in  Chicago,  wealthy  coastal  cities,  New  York,  San  Francisco,  LA,  even,  even  Chicago.

And  it,  those,  those,  those  facts  just  don't  comport  with  a  totally  equal  America,  right?  Yeah.  Why  the  debate  on  inequality  is  so  pervasive?  Because  the  debate  or  the  inequality  is  really  hitting  where  the  educated  class  is.

So  most  So  most  academics,  most  journalists,  most  talking  heads  are  not  particularly  tuning  in  with  the  bottom  20 %  of  the  income  distribution.  As  a  result,

they  don't  know  whether  they're  doing  better  or  worse.  But  we  are  very  tuning  in  from  the  middle  to  the  upper  part  of  the  income  distribution  and  that's  where  the  dramatic  changes  are  taking  place.

So  I  think  that  the  difference  difference  between  the  0 .1 %  and  the  10 %  has  increased  dramatically  over  the  last  three  decades.

And  so  if  you  were  in  the  top  90 %  of  the  income  distribution,  you  felt  like  very  rich  in  the  past.  And  today,  by  comparison  to  anybody  else,  you  feel  poor.

So  I  actually,  Luigi,  ended  up  thinking  that  his  whole  point  is  we  need  to  look  honestly  at  the  data,  even  when  the  data  isn't  what  you  want  to  believe.  believe.  You  need  to  look  honestly  at  the  data  so  we  can  have  a  real  policy  discussion.  And  I  absolutely  agree  with  that.

But  then  when  it  comes  to  looking  at  data,  he  doesn't  want  to  believe,  which  is  data  showing  that  people  who  are  working  full  time  and  really  trying  can't  make  ends  meet.  He  doesn't  want  to  acknowledge  that  because  that's  not  convenient  with  the  ideological  argument  that  the  only  problem  with  these  people  is  they  aren't  willing  to  get  off  their  butts.

And  that  bothers  me.  It  feels  hypocritical.  Yeah,  and  I  think  that  he  he  insists  very  much  on  the  correlation  between  increasing  these  payments  and  increasing  prime  age  workers  who  are  not  working,

but  he  knows  better  than  most  that  correlation  is  not  necessarily  causation.  And  he  doesn't  have  any  causal  evidence  of  that.  And  I  think  this  is  where  ideology  comes  in  the  picture.

I  think  that  he  likes  to  portray  a  certain...  certain  picture  without  really  having  the  data  to  back  it  up.  There  have  been  some  experiments  where  people  receive,  for  example,  some  transfer  and  see  what  impact  they  have  on  their  willingness  to  work.

I'm  not  an  expert  here,  but  the  majority  of  evidence  is  in  favor  that  the  effect  is  not  that  large  because  people  want  to  work  for  other  reasons.  I  think  he's  right.  One  point  where  he's  right  is  to  say  that  if  you  you  don't  work,

you  are  progressively  left  out  from  the  improvement  in  everything.  And  I  think  that  that's  actually,  if  you  want,  the  biggest  criticism  of  the  universal  basic  income,

that  if  you  think  that  you  are  going  to  solve  the  problem  by  letting  people  at  home,  these  people  will  become  increasingly  dissatisfied  and  increasingly  marginalized.  So  I  think  it's  very  important  to  get  everybody  the  opportunity  to  work,

but  the  conclusion  that  people  don't  want  to  work  because  it's  too  costly  for  them  to  work.  I  think  it's  a  perfectly  legitimate  conclusion  in  theory.  I  don't  think  it  applies  so  well  in  practice.

And  we  economists  are  the  worst  in  presuming  that  people  behave  according  to  our  model  rather  than  the  way  we  behave.  I  was  talking  with  a  colleague  and  this  colleague  would  say,  "Oh,  these  days,  if  I  don't  have  the  writing  standards,

I  don't  do  it."  anything."  I  said,  "Wait,  you  dedicate  most  of  your  time  to  the  school,  I  hope.  In  most  of  your  time,  yes,  you're  incentive,  you're  tenure.  There  is  nothing  that  pushes  you  to  work,

and  still  you  work  your  butt  off."  So  I  think  that  that's  the  proof  by  example  that  what  you're  saying  is  wrong.  I  would  agree  with  that.  I'd  also  add  one  wrinkle  to  it,

the  economists  and  maybe  journalists.  journalists  too,  I  don't  know,  maybe  journalists  are  better  at  this  than  economists  are.  Economists  are  also  the  worst,  assuming  that  what  is  a  motivation  for  one  person  must  be  a  motivation  for  somebody  else.

The  truth  is,  people  are  wildly  varied  in  people's  makeup  and  their  means  and  the  ways  they  react  to  things  are  actually  quite  individualistic.  It  might  be  true.  He  might  be  right.  For  one  person,

it  might  be  that  they're  making  enough  in  transfer  payments  that  they  don't  feel  the  need  to  get  a  job.  But  to  say  that  that's  true.  for  one  person  might  be  true  for  one  person  is  already  a  guess.  But  to  say  it's  true  for  the  population  at  large,

I  think  is  quite  tricky.  I  also  thought  on  a  slightly  different  note,  I  never  would  have  guessed  before  we  did  this  recording  that  Phil  Graham  and,  according  to  him,  Milton  Friedman  were  believers  in  UBI.

And  the  idea  that  he  might  be  a  believer  in  UBI,  it  flies  in  the  face  of  a  lot  of  what  he  was  saying  to  me  because  per  his  point,  people  who  don't  work  are  left  increasingly  behind  and  UBI  is  hugely  problematic  in  that  respect.

But  yet  here's  Phil  Graham  saying  that  maybe  UBI  is  better  than  what  we  do  now,  which  I  realize,  I'm  pushing  it  a  little  bit  by  saying  he  recommended  it.  That's  not  quite  what  he  said.  He  basically  said  it  might  be  a  better  alternative  to  what  we're  doing  and  I  actually  did  agree  with  that  point  of  his  that  we  are  spending  an  awful  lot  of  money  and  if  we're  spending  so  much  money.

money,  we  should  think  about  what  it's  doing.  And  that  was  a  side  point  of  what  he  said,  but  that's  true  too.  Yeah,  I  would  say,  first,  I  would  give  ourself,  and  this  is  ourself  as  US  government,  a  part  in  the  back  say,

we  are  doing  a  lot.  I  think  we  don't  hear  very  much.  I  think  that  there  is  all  this  criticism  about  government  and  doing  this,  doing  that.  In  this  particular  case,  the  war  on  poverty  actually  worked.

Isn't  that  interesting?  I  was  thinking  when  we  were  talking  to  him  that  I  would  have  rewritten  his  book  for  him  and  I  would  have  written  it  with  a  very  different  point,  at  least  at  the  beginning,

which  was  look  at  how  successful  the  war  on  poverty  has  been.  And  so  rather  than  a  title  saying  inequality  doesn't  exist,  I  would  have  put  a  title  on  it  saying,  "Look  at  our  great  success  and  how  well  we've  done."  And  he  would  have  gotten  a  lot  more  readers  that  way  and  you  could  have  made  all  the  same  points  just  in  a  slightly  different  order.

And  if  you  started  with  the  fact  that  there...  has  been  so  successful  and  then  went  into  what  it  means  for  the  future  and  what  it  means  for  actual  inequality  numbers,  I  think  he  would  have  gotten  a  lot  more  people  to  agree  with  him.  - Yeah,

and  the  point  is  interesting  because  one  natural  conclusion  of  your  kind  of  book  would  be  to  say,  why  don't  we  do  a  little  bit  more  and  actually  eradicate  poverty?  We  have  gone  pretty  close  to  do  it,

but  we  need  to  do  the  last  mile.  Now,  his  point,  which  is  a  little  bit  more  subtle,  is,  is  maybe  we  can  do  the  last  mile  in  the  same  way  which  we're  doing  that,

which  is  possible,  but  I'm  not  seeing  any  statistic  in  his  book  actually  making  that  in  a  convincing  way.  So  it  would  be  interesting  to  say,  look,

we  have  done  90 %  of  the  job  with  30 %  of  the  money,  but  the  last  70 %  is  really  not  doing  very  well.  I  think  that  would  be  a  a  very  interesting  book,

and  it's  not  in  this  book  as  far  as  I  know.  and  poverty  has  been  eradicated.

Okay,  not  quite,  but  close.  - We  promise  in  that  episode  that  there's  a  counter  to  Graham's  argument.  We'll  have  Matthew  Desmond,  who's  a  professor  of  sociology  at  Princeton.

His  previous  book  was  "Evicted,"  which  explored  the  ways  in  which  the  housing  system  reinforces  poverty  and  has  won  a  policy  prize  for  nonfiction.  Now  he  has  a  new  book  called  "Poverty  by  America,"  and  the  title  is  very  indicative,

is  not  "Poverty  in  America,"  but  "Poverty  by  America."  America.  And  as  you  probably  think,  his  argument  could  not  be  more  counter  to  Graham's  one.  In  effect,  he  argues  that  poverty  in  America  is  a  terrible  scooch  that  will  make  no  progress,

and  that's  a  moral  outrage.  He  writes  that  according  to  the  government's  official  poverty  measure,  there's  been  a  little  change  in  the  share  of  the  population  considered  poor  over  the  last  50  years.  12 .6 %  in  1970  and  30 %  in  America.

.5 %  two  decades  later.  And  by  2019,  he  was  still  10 .5%.  So  importantly,  Desmond  argues  the  numbers  aren't  the  only  way  to  define  poverty.

And  this  is  important.  He  writes,  "Poverty  isn't  simply  the  condition  of  not  having  enough  money.  It's  the  condition  of  not  having  enough  choice  and  being  taken  advantage  of  because  of  that.  It's  constant  worry  about  how  you're  going  to  pay  your  bills,

the  inability  to  think  about  anything  beyond  the  fear  of  the  present  moment."  moment.  People  have  called  this  the  bandwidth  tax.  And  Desmond  argues  that  partly  because  of  the  horrific  stress  caused  by  poverty,  it's  likely  to  become  a  vicious  trap.

But  here's  the  funny  thing.  Graham  and  Desmond  actually  agree  on  one  thing,  which  is  that  transfer  payment  have  increased  enormously.  Desmond  writes,  "If  America  poverty  persisted,  I  thought  it  was  because  we  had  reduced  our  spending  on  the  poor,

but  I  was  wrong.  Spending  on  the  nation."  nation's  13  largest  mean -tested  programs,  aid  reserve  for  Americans  who  fall  below  a  certain  income  level,  went  from  $1 ,050  a  person,

when  Reagan  was  president,  to  $3 ,419  a  person,  when  Donald  Trump  was  president,  a  237 %  increase.  - But  in  Desmond's  view,

this  hasn't  helped.  He  argues  that  the  money  doesn't  reach  all  the  people  who  are  eligible.  And  I  think  his  argument  is  that  that  poverty  is  more  than  a  number  is  really  convincing.  He  argues  that  the  primary  reason  for  our  stalled  progress  on  poverty  reduction  is  that  we  have  not  confronted  the  unrelenting  exploitation  of  the  poor  in  the  labor  housing  and  financial  markets  and  that's  because  more  fortunate  Americans

benefit  from  that  exploitation.  He  writes,  "Tens  of  millions  of  Americans  do  not  end  up  poor  by  a  mistake  of  history  or  personal  conduct.  Poverty  persists  because  some  wish  and  will  it  too."  So  there's  so  much  to  discuss  here,

but  let's  talk  to  Matthew  first.  - I  would  like  to  start  by  asking,  what  made  you  interested  in  the  question  of  poverty  to  begin  with?

- Well,  I  grew  up  poor.  I  grew  up  in  a  little  town  in  Arizona.  Families  gas  got  cut  off  regularly.  We  lost  our  childhood  home  to  foreclosure.  And  then  for  my  last  book,  "Convicted,"  I  moved  into  Milwaukee.

Milwaukee,  moved  into  a  mobile  home  park  and  a  rooming  house  on  the  north  side  of  the  city.  And  it's  mid -time  with  families  getting  evicted.  And  that's  where  I  saw  another  kind  of  poverty  that  I'd  never  experienced,  never  seen  before.

I  saw,  you  know,  grandmas  without  heat  in  the  winter.  I  saw  kids  routinely  evicted.  And  I  think  that  pressed  this  question  of  why  there's  so  much  poverty  in  this  rich  country  inside  of  me  in  a  deep  and  unique  way.

Now,  can  you  define  poverty  for  us?  Because  I  think  that  a  lot  depends  on  on  where  you  set  the  line  for  poverty,  right?  - Right,  so  officially  poverty  is  an  income  level.  The  American  official  poverty  measure  is  drawn  about  $27 ,000,

$28 ,000  a  year  for  a  family  of  four.  The  supplemental  poverty  measure  is  a  little  higher  between  $31 ,000  and  $33 ,000  a  year  for  a  family  of  four.  You  know,  you  get  10  scholars  in  a  room  and  they're  gonna  argue  about  the  measurement.

But  I  think  that  everyone  agrees  it's  too  low.  - Yeah,  it's  too  low.  but  that  doesn't  even  rush  the  surface,  right?  And  I  think  that  those  of  us  that  have  spent  a  lot  of  time  in  poor  neighborhoods  know  that  poverty  isn't  just  the  lack  of  money.

It's  like  chronic  pain  on  top  of  exposure  to  violence  and  crime  often,  on  top  of  eviction  and  homelessness,  hunger,  death,  you  know?  And  so  I  think  that  this  recognition  that  poverty  is  this  tight  knot  of  social  maladies  and  humiliations  is  really  important  for  like  great  the  stakes  of  the  problem  and  really  making  an  argument  for  the  moral  urgency  of  how  much  of  an  abomination  poverty  really  is.

So  I  think  the  point  that  you  make  that  poverty  isn't  just  a  number  that  we  need  a  much  broader  definition  of  it  really  resonated  with  me.  At  the  same  time,  there  is,  for  lack  of  a  better  way  of  putting  it,

a  sleight  of  hand  of  sorts  in  your  analysis  because  you  argue  that  poverty  based  on  income  hasn't  budged.  Even  the  though  transfer  payments  have  increased  dramatically  because  those  transfer  payments  aren't  included  in  the  income  levels.

So  do  you  think  that's  an  issue  with  relying  on  income  levels  to  define  poverty  or  would  you  argue  that  it's  immaterial  given  all  these  other  factors  that  make  up  poverty?  So  there's  not  a  sleight  of  hand  in  the  book.

There's  just  the  editorial  decision  and  there's  a  ton  of  footnotes,  right?  And  the  footnotes  use  different  poverty  measures  and  those  different  poverty  measures  show  that  the  percentage  of  people  who  are  in  poverty  is  the  same  as  those  who  are  in  poverty.  of  poverty  over  the  last  50  years,

even  in  the  face  of  rising  government  spending.  And  this  is  a  paradox  I  think  we  have  to  lean  into,  I  think,  because  there's  a  ton  of  evidence  that  shows  that  government  programs  work,  they're  essential,  they're  important.

There's  also  a  ton  of  evidence  that  spending  and  investments  on  the  13th  biggest  means  tested  programs,  in  any  case,  have  grown,  right?  So,  first  year  in  Toronto  Reagan's  administration,

we  spent  around  $1 ,000  per  person  on  those  programs.  And  the  first  year  in  a  dental  trumps,  we  spent  about  $3 ,400  per  person  on  those  programs,  adjusted  for  inflation.  It's  a  237 %  increase.  And  so  if  you  look  at  the  official  poverty  measure,

it's  been  stagnant,  but  it's  a  flawed  measure.  It  doesn't  account  for  a  lot  of  that  spending.  But  if  you  look  at  the  historical  supplemental  poverty  measure,  which  does  account  for  a  lot  of  those  transfers  and  taxes,  you  get  the  same  results.

So  50  years  ago,  1973,  1973,  the  historical  SPM  is  about  15%.  Fast  forward  40  years,  it's  about  15%.  It  dips  a  little  before  the  pandemic.

And  then  of  course  it  plunges,  right?  Because  of  this  historic  investment  in  the  American  people  by  the  federal  government.  But  now  it's  creeping  back  up.  That's  the  paradox  I  think  we  have  to  embrace  if  we're  gonna  solve  poverty.

And  I  think  that  the  solution  to  the  paradox  or  one  kind  of  solution  to  that  puzzle  is  that,  you  know,  the  fundamentals  of  American  society  are  breaking  down,  especially  in  the  labor  market  and  the  housing  market  for  the  American  poor,

and  it  kind  of  is  a  recipe  for  spinning  more  to  stay  in  the  same  place.  So  let's  get  into  the  weeds  just  a  little  bit  if  you  don't  mind.  So  like  when  the  war  on  poverty  was  launched  in  1964,

the  Great  Society,  one  in  three  American  workers  belonged  to  a  labor  union.  Real  wages  were  climbing  every  year.  And  so  in  that  kind  of  scenario,  those  investments  were  cures.  But  as  workers  lost  power  and  our  jobs  got  a  lot  worse  and  wages  have  stagnated,

those  programs  have  turned  into  something  like  dialysis.  They're  incredibly  helpful  and  meaningful,  but  they're  not  lifting  a  lot  of  folks  out  of  poverty  in  a  permanent  way  because  the  job  market  and  housing  market  continue  to  be  pretty  exploitive.

Federal  housing  spending  has  increased  about  15 %  since  2000.  2000  in  real  terms.  And  so  we  might  think,  oh,  15 %  more  families  are  being  served,  but  that's  not  true.  It's  about  4 .5  million  families  in  2000,

and  it's  about  4 .5  million  families  today.  So  why?  And  it's  because  the  rents  have  basically  increased  that  much  during  that  time.  And  if  many  of  our  government  programs  are  public -private  investments  that  subsidize  the  private  market,

then  that's  a  recipe  for  spending  more  to  stay  in  the  same  place.  So  I'm  going  to  posit  something  somewhat  shocking,  which  is  that  in  a  really  odd  way  you  infill  ground.  Graham  actually  seem  to  agree,  which  is  that  you  both  argue  that  transfer  payments  haven't  accomplished  what  they  should  have,

given  that  they  haven't  gotten  more  Americans  to  be  able  to  make  more  money.  Now,  he's  got  a  very  different  set  of  policy  prescriptions  than  you  do.  His  policy  prescriptions  are  essentially  get  rid  of  transfer  payments,  so  people  have  to  go  earn  money.

But  what  do  you  say  about  just  this  broad  notion  that  you  guys  actually  do  agree  that  transfer  payments  haven't  accomplished  what  they  should?  Well,  I  think  for  those  of  us  us  that  are  seeking  to  end  poverty,  it's  a  challenge  and  it's  a  paradox.

And  I  don't  think  we  can  run  away  from  it,  actually,  or  adjust  the  inflation  measure  in  a  way  that  tells  a  different  story.  I  think  we  really  need  to  look  hard  on  it.  If  you  just  look  at  normal  hardship  measures,  it's  really  troubling.

Eviction  filings  were  up  22 %  over  the  last  20  years.  The  number  of  families  who  visited  food  pantries  up  19%.  The  number  of  homeless  school  kids  up  74 %  since  the  Great  Recession  recession,  real  troubling,

hard  measures.  That's  really  difficult  to  dismiss.  And  so  I  think  that  this  book  is  asking  for  more  or  not  less.  It  has  a  recognition  of  the  power  and  importance  and  just  life -saving  benefits  of  many  of  these  programs.

I  mean,  I've  been  with  families  when  they  receive  a  housing  voucher,  and  they  just  like  fall  to  the  knees  and  weep,  you  know,  because  they  know  that  it's  a  lifesaver.  lifesaver.  And  the  evidence  of  what  those  families  do  when  they  finally  receive  that  voucher  after  years  and  years  on  the  waiting  list  is  moving  to  me,

they  take  it  to  the  grocery  store,  you  know,  they  buy  more  food,  their  kids  become  less  anemic.  And  so  arguments  about  taking  away  those  programs  or  doing  less  for  those  families  are  pretty  insensitive  and  out  of  touch.

And  sometimes  you  can  cruel,  I  think,  but  I  also  think...  we  have  to  recognize  that  we  don't  just  need  more  of  the  same.  We  need  different  policies,  policies  to  disrupt  poverty,  and  especially  policies  that  attack  exploitation  and  the  financial  and  housing  markets.

And  so  I  think  that  that  paradox  is  something  that  we  should  start  leaning  into  and  confronting  because  it  has  real  policy  implications,  right?  It  means  that  we  don't  just  need  an  expanded  EITC,

for  example,  which  I  would  be  for.  But  we  also  should  be  pushing  for  things  like  secretarial  bargaining  and  worker  empowerment.  When  it  comes  to  transfer,  I  would  have  expected  you  to  say  that  maybe  we  should  be  reallocating  them  because  it  seems  to  me  that  a  lot  of  the  transfer  end  up  going  mostly  to  older  people  and  young  people  and  kids  and  etc.

are  short  change  in  the  equation.  So,  not  that  all  the...  people  don't  need  help,  but  I  think  that  they  are  a  much  more  powerful  coalition  and  end  up  receiving  a  lot  of  it.

The  way  I  would  frame,  but  feel  free  to  disagree,  is  we  need  to  be  more  targeted  in  our  help.  - So  I  remember  being  at  a  policy,  the  Kennedy  School  and  a  colleague  turned  to  me  and  he  said,

you  know,  would  you  rather  have  twice  as  many  housing  vouchers,  but  they're  worth  half  as  much,  you  know?  These  kinds  of  questions,  trade -off  questions.  These  are  serious  questions.  I  think  we  should  pursue  them.  The  book  rejects  them  though,  in  a  way.

The  book  is  like,  these  are  scarcity  mindset  questions.  Do  we  have  to  choose  in  America  to  support  our  elderly  population  or  support  our  kids?  I  don't  think  we  do.  There's  this  one  study  that  I  just  can't  get  over,

which  shows  that  if  the  top  1 %  of  Americans  just  pay  the  taxes  they  owed,  such  evading  taxes  as  successfully,  we  could  raise  an  additional  $175  billion  each.  year,  right?  That's  enough  to  reestablish  a  child  tax  credit  that  cut  child  poverty  by  46 %  during  COVID.

That's  enough  to  double  our  investment  in  affordable  housing.  That's  basically  enough  to  pull  everyone  above  the  official  poverty  line.  It's  a  rough  estimate,  but  it  shows  that  I  don't  think  we  have  to  back  ourselves  in  the  scarcity  corner  where  we're  choosing  between  kids  and  elderly  folks.

I  think  that  we  do  have  to  advocate  for  policies  that  result  in  the  richest  among  us  taking  less  from  the  government.  You  know,  policies  that  invest  deeper  in  fighting  poverty  instead  of  guarding  fortunes  or  subsidizing  affluence.

So  one  of  the  important  factors  that  you  point  out,  which  I  think  is  very  important,  is  the  cost  of  housing.  By  and  large,  the  cost  of  housing  is  driven  by  resistance  in  building  more,

not  in  my  backyard  policy,  have  been  really  a  major  obstacle.  to  the  supply  of  new  constructions,  and  that  has  increased  dramatically  the  cost  of  rental.

But  I  also  feel  that  we  know  a  lot  less  about  what's  driving  higher  rents  than  I  think  we  think  we  do.  And  I  think  that  in  some  cities,  the  lack  of  supply  is  clearly  the  story.

But  many  cities,  Toledo,  Tucson,  Houston  even  have  have  decent  vacancy  rates  and  are  still  seeing  real  pressures  on  the  rents.  And  some  of  the  highest  evicting  cities  in  the  country,

Richmond,  Virginia,  Tulsa,  Oklahoma,  Albuquerque,  New  Mexico,  Wilmington,  Delaware,  are  not  cities  that  are  suffering  from  the  kinds  of  housing  crisis  that  we  see  in  the  coastal  big  cities.  And  so  I  think  that  there  are  many  drivers  to  the  rental  crisis  that  aren't  fully  understood  yet,

actually.  but  I  think  that  attacking  exclusionary  zoning,  both  as  a  policy  point,  but  also  just  as  a  cultural  change  and  building  the  political  will  that  allows  neighborhoods  not  to  let  their  property  lines  dictate  where  their  values  stop  is  really  important.

One  of  the  arguments  of  the  book  is  about  exploitation  and  the  housing  crisis.  One  of  the  things  that  I  was  really  binopeling  to  me,  I  was  living  in  a  mobile  home  park  in  Milwaukee,

and  the  landlord  let  me  see  his.  rent  books  so  I  could  calculate  his  bottom  line.  And  I  learned  that  the  landlord  that  I  was  rented  from,  which  was  a  really  poor  mobile  home  park  in  the  fourth  poor  city  in  the  country  at  the  time,

he  was  making  over  $400 ,000  a  year  after  expenses.  And  so  that  set  him  in  a  completely  different  life  than  many  of  us  tenants  who  are  on  disability  or  working  minimum  wage.  And  that  me  thinking  like  how  unique  is  that?

And  we  actually  have  data  for  that.  It's  called  the  Rental  Housing  Finance  Survey.  And  it's  a  nationwide  survey  of  landlords.  Not  perfect,  but  it's  pretty  good.  And  if  you  look  at  that  data,  you  learn  that  landlords  in  poor  neighborhoods  have  much  higher  margins  than  landlords  in  middle  class  neighborhoods.

They  don't  make  just  more.  They  make  double  often.  When  you  have  a  captive  tenant  group  that  doesn't  have  a  lot  of  choice,  then  you  can  charge  them  more  for  less.  In  2020,  the  United  States  spent  about  $193  billion  on  homeowner  tax  subsidies.

[MUSIC  PLAYING]  about  $53  billion  on  direct  housing  assistance  to  the  needy.  Most  of  those  homeowner  tax  subsidies  just  accrued  to  rich  families,  the  top  20 %  of  families.  And  we  do  have  agreement  in  economics  that  the  things  like  the  mortgage  interest  deduction  does  not  increase  homeownership.

It  just  makes  our  homes  more  valuable  than  they  would  be  without  it.  So  for  me,  this  is  a  clearly  regressive  imbalance  in  the  tax  code.  It's  interesting  about  homeownership  as  a  solution  to  the  affordable  housing  crisis  is  that  in  a  lot  of  markets,

it's  much  cheaper  to  own  your  home  than  to  rent.  I  remember  meeting  a  woman  named  Higby  that  I  write  about  in  the  book.  She  was  in  Cleveland  working  for  Amazon  as  a  picker,  and  she  was  paying,  I  think,  $950  a  month  to  rent  a  four -bedroom  home  in  Cleveland.

But  if  she  bought  that  home  under  conventional  mortgage  standards,  her  mortgage  payment  and  insurance  would  be  about  $500.  a  month.  It's  like  $4 ,500  more  in  her  pocket  every  year  with  no  writ  hikes.  So  she  could  afford  it,

so  to  speak.  There's  just  no  odd  ramps  for  someone  like  IKEA  because  banks  aren't  super  interested  in  small -dollar  mortgages.  Not  because  they're  riskier,  the  data  suggests  that  they're  not,  but  they're  less  profitable.

You  could  just  make  a  lot  more  money  issuing  a  million -dollar  mortgage  than  a  $75 ,000  mortgage.  This  is  why  the  books  suggest  on -ramps  to  homeownership  for  low -income  families  as  one  of  many  solutions  to  the  housing  crisis.

Last  year,  27 %  of  homes  sold  for  $100 ,000  or  less,  affordable  homes,  but  only  23 %  of  those  were  financed  with  a  mortgage.  So  I  think  this  is  another  place  that  we  can  kind  of  help  with  down  payment  assistance  and  incentivize  lending  institutions  to  get  more  of  those  families  like  Lakeos  into  homes  like  that.

I  agree  with  you  on  homeownership.  I  think  it's  also  a  solution  to  what's  are  partly  a  solution  to  what's  going  to  be  a  retirement  crisis,  right?  If  you  have  a  whole  subset  of  Americans  getting  to  retirement  age  and  they  don't  have  a  home  in  which  to  retire,

then  you  have  a  mammoth  problem.  And  Luigi  and  I've  talked  about  this  before  on  the  podcast,  the  idea  that  home  ownership  for  poor  people  was  responsible  for  the  financial  crisis  in  2008  is  just  one  of  the  worst  tropes  that's  been  put  out  there  because  it's  just,

it's  completely  wrong.  So  I've  ended  up  thinking  after  this  kind  of,  that  maybe  part  of  our  problem  is  a  measurement  problem  and  maybe  we  need  to  scrap  all  these  measures  like  the  poverty  line  and  the  supplemental  poverty  measure  and  focus  instead  on  these  numbers  that  you  outline  like  whether  evictions  are  going  up  and  children  living  in  homeless  situations  and  food  shortages  and  define  them  in  a  very  granular  way  and

just  get  rid  of  these  big  picture  statistics  that  can  both  be  misused  and  that  may  not  actually  be.  be  telling  us  anything.  So  what  do  you  think  about  that  idea?  Let's  just  start  from  scratch,  scrap  it  all,

and  come  up  with  a  new  definition  of  what  poverty  actually  is.  - I  think  there's  really  something  to  that,  you  know,  and  I  think  that  if  we  wanna  measure  hardship,  let's  measure  hardship,  and  let's  kind  of  come  together  and  agree  on  a  set  of  indicators  about  human  flourishing  and  basic  necessities,

and  let's  track  those.  I  think  that  that  gives  a  real  texture  and  reflection  of  the  lived  experience  of  poverty,  in  a  way.  that  the  poverty  line  doesn't.  And  the  poverty  line  too,  it's  just,  it's  very  susceptible  to  manipulation  and  change.

You  can  tell  really  different  stories  about  poverty,  depending  on  the  inflation  measures  you  used  over  the  last  50  years,  or  if  you're  anchored  or  not.  And  so  I  think  that  gets  you  into  these  debates  about  completely  different  Americas  in  a  way,

but  it's  just  based  on  really  technical  things.  And  so  I  like  that  idea.  I  think  England  does  this.  this.  One  of  the  measures  that  England  uses  is  I  think  they  have  a  20  or  so  point  scale  about  child  poverty  that  they  use  to  kind  of  measure  hardship.

I  think  adopting  that  over  here  makes  a  lot  of  sense.  Thank  you  so  much  for  your  time  and  for  your  work.  No,  thanks  both.  I  mean,  thanks  for  doing  such  great  homework  and  thanks  for  having  me  on.  I  really  appreciated  this  conversation.

So,  Luigi,  who  did  you  end  up  agreeing  with  more?  Mark,  Graham  or  Desmond,  or  maybe  a  better  way  to  ask  the  question  is,  did  Desmond  change  the  way  you  thought  about  Graham's  analysis?

That's  a  very  good  question.  Yes.  First  of  all,  the  analysis  is  different  in  so  many  dimensions  that  it's  really,  I  think  we  should  congratulate  ourselves  to  pair  the  two  because  together  they're  very  useful.

I  think  Graham  is  all  about  numbers,  and  I  think  he's  right  with  the  numbers,  but  as  Mark  Twain  said,  you  can  lie  with  the  statistics.  very  effectively,  so  don't  give  a  full  picture.  The  thing  that  I  like  the  most  of  Desmond  is  when  he  talks  about  the  friction  that  makes  poverty  structural,

so  the  screw  up  in  the  tax  system,  the  lack  of  competition  or  access  to  credit  in  housing,  these  are  structural  problems  that  have  nothing  to  do  with  transfer.

It's  very  hard  to  disagree  with  Desmond  on  those  issues.  issues.  In  America,  we  did  make  significant  improvement  in  fighting  poverty,  but  not  enough.  And  particularly,

a  lot  of  money  is  misallocated.  One  of  the  factoids  that  Desmond  was  citing  is  how  much  money  that  is  dedicated  to  fight  poverty  end  up  in  somebody's  hands,  which  is  a  serious  problem.

And  how  many  other  things  on  the  margin  we  can  do  to  make  this  society  more...  welcoming  and  giving  more  opportunities  to  everybody,  which  is  something  that  also  Senator  Graham  wanted  to  do.

Yeah.  I  was  stunned  by  one  number  in  his  book  in  particular,  and  there  were  bigger  numbers,  but  the  number  that  just  jumped  out  at  me  was  that  a  billion  dollars  of  social  security  disability  payments  go  into  the  hands  of  lawyers  because  anybody  who  needs  a  social  security  disability  payment  knows  that  you're  not  going  to  get  it  at  first  and  that  eventually  you  have  to  hire  a  lawyer  and  the  lawyer  is  going  to  take  a

portion  of  the  money  you  get.  And  I  thought,  that  if  there's  anything  that  sums  up  the  exploitation  more,  then  it's  that  it's  that  it's  that.  So  Luigi,  one  thing  that  I'm  still  struggling  with  is  how  they  can  both  be  right.

How  can  Graham's  numbers  be  right?  And  I  think  most  people  agree  that  the  numbers  are  right,  even  if  we  don't  agree  with  the  story  they  tell.  But  how  can  Graham's  numbers  be  right?  And  yet  Desmond  can  have  all  these  heartbreaking  examples  of  really  extreme  poverty.

How  can  those  two  things  coexist  at  the  same  time?  So  I'm  looking  at  Phil  Graham's  number.  And  think  about  the  bottom  quintile  of  the  income  distribution.  You  see  that  we  see  $41 ,000  a  year,

but  of  this  $41 ,000,  $16 ,000,  $17 ,000  is  Medicare,  Medicaid.  And  another  $10 ,000  is  Social  Security.  So  basically,  for  the  old  people  who  are  not  necessarily  poor.

because  they  might  own  a  house  and  then  might  have  some  wealth,  etc.,  but  they  are  in  the  bottom  20 %  of  the  income  distribution,  you  have  a  lot  of  help.  And  part  of  that  $10 ,000  in  Medicaid  and  $8 ,000  in  Medicare,

those  are  also,  I'm  sorry  to  say,  but  the  all  the  money  that  you  spend  in  the  last  30  days  of  your  life  where  you  spend  the  fortune,  right?  The  statistics  are  that  enormous  amount  of  money  is  spent  there.  So  that  money  does  not  really  translate  into  helping  the  single  mother  with  a  kid  struggling.

So  if  you  are  a  single  mother  and  you're  trying  to  raise  a  kid  and  try  to  work  at  the  same  time,  you  don't  get  social  security  for  sure,  you  don't  get  Medicare,  maybe  we  get  Medicaid  and  some  food  stamps,  but  the  food  stamps  at  the  end  of  the  day  are  only  $1 ,500  on  average.

So  they're  not  that  much.  So  the  big  chunk  is  social  security  and  Medicare,  Medicaid.  And  those  are  certainly  social  security  and  Medicare,  mostly  for  the  elderly.

That's  the  reason  why  I  asked  this  question  about  the  misallocation.  So  I  think  that  there  is  a  tale  because  if  you're  temporarily  poor  and  if  you've  made  a  lot  of  money  through  your,

a  lot  of  money,  you've  made  a  decent  amount  of  money  through  your  life,  you  own  a  house  and  now  you're  not  making  a  lot  of  money.  but  you're  receiving  a  lot  of  subsidy  in  Medicare  is  one  thing,  and  that  doesn't  compensate  for  the  poor  people  who  don't  receive  anything.

And  I  think  it  just  points  to  this  idea  that  these  top -line  measures  of  poverty  are  just  so  flawed  is  to  be  almost  useless,  because  any  top -line  measure  encompasses  such  different  sets  of  people  and  such  different  sets  of  money  that  they're  that  they're  getting  or  not  getting,

that  it  is  almost,  it's  almost  irreplaceable.  when  it  comes  to  the  lived  experience  of  poverty.  with  production  assistants  from  Udesof  Gandhi,

Sebastian  Burka,  and  Brooke  Fox.  Don't  forget  to  subscribe  and  leave  a  review  wherever  you  get  your  podcasts.